Network and Positive Feedback Introduction
- The industrial economy was populated by oligopoly industries in which a few large firms dominate markets.
- Examples of oligopolies include:
Automobiles industry
Steel industry
Aluminum industry
Various chemical markets - The difference is that the old industrial economy was driven by economics of scale while the new information economy is driven by the economics of network, called positive feedback.
- Many information goods are also characterized by network externalities: the value of the good to an individual is greater when a large number of people use it. It means, “The value of connecting to a network depends on the number of other people already connected to it”
- This fundamental value proposition is also known as network effect, or network externalities, or demand side economics of scale
They are essentially refer the same thing: other things being equal, it’s better to be connected to a bigger network than a smaller one.
Types of Feedback
In network externalities, two types of feedback generally known are of Positive feedback and Negative feedback
Positive feedback makes the strong get stronger and the weak get weaker, leading to extreme outcomes i.e. dominance of the market
place by a single firm or technology. Positive feedback illustrates that success beget success and failure breeds failure. In its most extreme form, positive feedback can lead to a winner-take-all market in which a single firm or technology vanquishes all others.
Negative Feedback makes the strong get weaker and the weaker get stronger, pushing both towards a happy medium. For example, the industrial oligopolies exhibit negative feedback.
- In a negative-feedback system, the strong get weaker and the weak get stronger
- larger firms became burdened with high costs, while smaller firms found profitable niches
Positive feedback
- old industrial economy was driven by economics of scale while the new information economy is driven by the economics of network, called positive feedback
- networks have a fundamental economic characteristic: the value of connecting to a network depends on the number of other people already connected to it
- Positive feedback makes the strong get stronger and the weak get weaker
- Dominance of market by a single firm or a technology
- Market is tippy
- it can tip in favor of one player or another. It is unlikely that all will survive
- Positive-feedback systems follow a predictable pattern
a. flat during launch, then
b. a steep rise during takeoff as positive feedback kicks in
c. leveling off as saturation is reached
Demand-side economies of scale
- In the information economy, positive feedback has appeared in a new, more virulent form based on the demand side of the market, not just the supply side
- Microsoft’s dominance is based on demand-side economies of scale. Microsoft’s customers value its operating systems because they are widely used
- positive relationship between popularity and value
- Popularity Adds Value in a Network Industry
- Supply side economies of scale
- Effect of declining average cost with increased quantity
- double whammy
- Mixture of supply side and demand side economies of scale in which growth on the demand side both reduces cost on the supply side and makes the product more attractive to other users
Network externalities
- Information product
- large networks are more attractive to users than small ones
- Network externalities, usefully highlights two aspects of information systems crucial for competitive strategy
- Network.
- Collection of users, managed by a sponsor
- Externalities
- consequence of an economic activity experienced by unrelated third parties
- Network.
- Negative externality
- economic activity that imposes a negative effect on an unrelated third party
- can arise either during the production or the consumption of a good or service.
- Pollution is termed an externality because it imposes costs on people who are “external” to the producer and consumer of the polluting product
Collective Switching Costs
- Challenge to companies seeking to introduce new but incompatible technology into the market
- to build network size by overcoming the collective switching costs—that is, the combined switching costs of all users
- Convincing ten people connected in a network to switch to your incompatible network is more than ten times as hard as getting one customer to switch
- Control over a large installed base of users can be the greatest asset you can have
Igniting positive feedback: performance vs. compatibility
- There are two basic approaches for dealing with the problem of consumer inertia
- evolution strategy of compatibility
- Revolution strategy of compelling performance
- Revolution
- Wipe the slate clean and come up with the best product possible
- Evolution
- give up some performance to ensure compatibility and thus ease consumer adoption
Evolution Strategy
- Focus on offering consumers an easy migration path
- centers on reducing switching costs so that consumers can gradually try your new technology
- The key to the evolution strategy is to build a new network by linking it first to the old one
- To lure customers, the migration path must be smooth
Obstacles of Evolution
- Technical Obstacles
- Early 1990s, the Europeans promoted a standard for the transmission of HDTV signals that conventional TV sets could decipher.
- But, the signal was not as sharp as true HDTV, and the technology was in difficulty
- Basic compatibility is not enough sometimes. We require a fair bit of performance too
- Legal Obstacles
- need to obtain the legal right to sell products that are compatible with the established installed base of products
- intellectual property rights over an older generation of technology
Strategies for smooth user migration paths to newer technologies
- Use creative design
- Good engineering and product design can greatly ease the compatibility/performance trade-off
- Think in terms of the system
- User cares with whole system despite the fact that we manufacture one component
- Consider converters and bridge technologies
- Example
- Purchase of digital signal converters by analog TV owners for compatibility of HDTV technology
- Example
Revolution: offer compelling performance
- Revolution strategy involves brute force:
- Offer a product so much better than what people are using that enough users will bear the pain of switching to it
- first attracting customers who care the most about performance and working down from there to the mass market
- Trick
- Offer compelling performance to first attract pioneering and influential users,
- then use this base to start up a bandwagon propelled by self-fulfilling consumer beliefs in the inevitable success of your product
- HDTV set manufacturers are hoping to first sell to the so-called vidiots, those who simply must have the very best quality video and the largest TV sets available
- If the market is growing rapidly, or if consumer lock-in is relatively mild, performance looms larger relative to backward compatibility
- Revolution strategy is inherently risky.
- It cannot work on a small scale
- Difficult to tell early on whether your technology will take off or crash
- So, it is better to start off slowly and accelerate from there
Igniting positive feedback: openness vs. control
- Anyone launching a new technology must also face a second fundamental trade-off, in addition to the performance/compatibility trade-off
- Do we choose an “open” approach by offering to make the necessary interfaces and specifications available to others,
- or do you attempt to maintain control by keeping your system proprietary?
- In choosing between openness and control,
- Your ultimate goal is to maximize the value of your technology, not your control over it
- Your reward = (Total value added to industry) x (your share of industry value)
- openness emphasize the first term in this formula
- Total value added to the industry.
- Strategies to achieve control emphasize the second term
- Your share of industry value
Trade-off between openness and control
Openness
- If the new technology draws on contributions from several different companies, each agrees to sacrifice control over its piece in order to create an attractive package:
- Principle: the whole is greater than the sum of the parts.
Approaches of Openness
- Under Full openness approach,
- anybody has the right to make products complying with the standard, whether they contributed to its development or not.
- Under An alliance approach,
- Each member of the alliance contributes something toward the standard, and, in exchange, each is allowed to make products complying with the standard.
- In other words, the alliance members all have guaranteed (usually free) access to the network they have created, but outsiders may be blocked from accessing it or required to pay a special fee for such access.
Control
- Only those in the strongest position can hope to exert strong control over newly introduced information technologies
- Companies strong enough to unilaterally control product standards and interfaces have power
- however, they have much to lose by promoting poorly conceived standards
- Examples:
- VISA , Microsoft, Intel, Apple, etc.
- Proprietary control will be exceedingly valuable if your product or system takes off
- You do not face rivals who can offer products to locked-in customers
- Network is far more valuable if you can control the ability of others to interconnect with you
- However, failure to open up a technology can spell its demise, if consumers fear lock-in or if you face a strong rival whose system offers comparable performance but is nonproprietary
Generic strategies in network markets
- Performance Play
- Involves the introduction of a new, incompatible technology over which the vendor retains strong proprietary control
- Makes the most sense if your advantage of a striking new technology that offers users substantial advantages over existing technology
- Entrants and upstarts with compelling new technology can more easily afford to ignore backward compatibility
- Controlled Migration
- consumers are offered a new and improved technology that is compatible with their existing technology, but is proprietary
- Open Migration
- new product is supplied by many vendors and requires little by way of switching costs
- makes the most sense if your advantage is primarily based on manufacturing capabilities.
- In that case, you will benefit from a larger total market and scale economies to shine
- Discontinuity
- New product or technology is incompatible with existing technology but is available from multiple suppliers
- favors suppliers that are either efficient manufacturers or that are best provide value-added services or software enhancements (in the case of software)
Metcalfe’ Law
- Named After Bob Metcalfe, the inventor of Ethernet.
- Value of a network of a network goes up as a square of a number of users
- If there are n people in a network, and the value of the network to each of them is proportional to the number of other users, then
- The total value of the network is n2
- If the value of a network to a single user is $1 for each other user on the network, then a network of size 10 has a total value of roughly $100. In contrast, a network of size 100 has a total value of roughly $10,000.
- More the users, more connections or linkage
- More linkage, more value to the network
- But eliminate copy of connections and own’s connection too
- Formula
- If n users exists, then
- Connections = (n(n-1))/2
- If n users exists, then
Historical examples of positive feedback: Telephone networks and interconnection
- Story begins in the mid-1890s, when several key Bell patents expired and the country emerged from a depression, causing independent(non-Bell) companies to proliferate. By 1903, Bell companies controlled less than half of the phones in America.
- emergence of a dominant national telephone company, the Bell System?
- In 1900, a mere 3percent of all calls were long distance.
- Most people did not care much about long-distance service
- many telephone companies did not even offer long-distance service
- long-distance capability was a technical problem of some magnitude.
- The Bell System had most extensive long-distance network
- At first, Bell allowed only its affiliates to have access to its long-distance network.
- After 1900, Bell hit upon the winning strategy: open up to nonaffiliated companies that met Bell’s technical and operating standards and that were not direct local competitors.
- This strategy stimulated traffic throughout the Bell network,
- Enhanced the value of Bell service by increasing the number of parties that could be reached,
- made Bell stronger versus the independents where Bell faced local competition.
- Bell implemented the loading coil in the system, which greatly enhanced its long-distance capabilities.
- Bell was able to charge more than rival independents for its local service
- Bell also remained attractive because of its ability to connect long-distance calls.
- Bell even controlled key cities.
- These advantages allowed the Bell System to grow into the dominant local and long-distance carrier
- It denied local rivals access to its long-distance network, arguing that interconnection with independents with inferior standards (driven by competition) could compromise the integrity of its entire network
- After 1907, AT&T bought out many of its local competitors
- These acquisitions were accepted to support universal service, at the expense of competition.
- The economic lesson from this story:
- If you control a key interface or bottleneck, you should open it up, but on your own terms and conditions.
- These include technical conditions necessary to preserve the integrity of your product and economic terms that compensate you for any foregone business. The early
- Bell System story also illustrates how control of certain key customers (for example, New York and Chicago) can be utilized into a dominant market position in the presence of network effects